Small (and getting smaller) parties

In a previous post I noted a growing gap between parties above the threshold of electability and those below, one that was unusual by Slovakia’s standards.  Thanks to the generosity of UVVM, FOCUS and IVO, which opened various archives to me during my time in Slovakia, I can now show a much longer time series (though numbers before 1999 are sketchier than those after because of a relative dearth of polls and less systematic methods of reporting.

Here is the development of the gap over time between the smallest “viable” party (i.e. one with more than 5%) and the largest “non-viable” party (i.e. one with less than 5%):

Viability gap in Slovakia, 1990-2008

Something is clearly changing.  With the exception of a few surveys in 1999 (like the result of the temporary consolidation of small parties into the Slovak Democratic Coalition) there were very few gaps larger than 5% from Slovakia’s first election in 1990 until its most recent in 2006 (in fact only one in twenty polls during that period showed such a large gap) whereas since 2006 there are almost no gaps smaller than 5% (only about one in ten).  In fact the band around the threshold of viability now utterly empty: since the 2006 election not a single party has had a monthly polling average in the range between 3.3% and 7.2%. Not one.

As might be expected, the gap has meant a sharp reduction in the overall share of preferences received by small parties.  The graph below shows the same trend.

Sum of Preferences for Small Parties in Slovakia

Small parties used to collect about 10%-20% but this is no longer the case.  The total number of preferences for parties below the 5% threshold in August 2008 was 4.2%. Put in other words, even if all the supporters for obscure parties banded together (not very likely), they would not together have enough to cross the threshold. Between the 1990 and 2006 elections only 17 of the 161 months with surveys showed a sum below 5%; since the 2006 elections only 1 of the 26 months shows a sum above 5%.

There is no single clear explanation for this change but there are several reasons that might make sense:

  • Smer and SDKU have “mopped up” several of the smaller parties (and the re-unification of SNS helped in this direction as well).
  • Voters have finally decided that they do not want to “waste” their votes on small parties (though of course “waste” is a contentious term in itself since there are reasons to vote for parties that have nothing to do with those parties’ chances for election to parliament).  Evidence from recent IVO surveys shows that voters think consciously about the support received by the party they intend to vote for and are less likely to vote for a party that might not get elected (preferring to give their votes to an electable second choice).  Unfortunately we do not have older data on this and cannot easily perform a time series.
  • Media and financial structures have come to play such a strong role in party choice that small parties which cannot get media attention or financial sponsorship cannot attract meaningful support and drop from the public radar screen.

The current “all-or-nothing” pattern of party support does not mean that there is no chance for new parties, but it does suggest that it is even more difficult for a party to to climb its way up from below as KSS did in 2002.  As before, new parties will need to drop in from above as big splinters of even bigger parties with dissatisfied electorates (DU, and to some extent ZRS and Smer) or as saviors (Smer, ANO, SOP).

And yet more populism (now in Slovak!)

Slovak Academy of Sciences, Sociological Institute, 25.06.2008

Many thanks to Zuzana Kusa and the researchers at the Sociological Institute of the Slovak Academy of Sciences for hosting a lively discussion on populism, with the best and most challenging questions yet. Dakujem.

Tu je powerpoint (po slovensky):
http://www.la.wayne.edu/polisci/kdk/populism/SU SAV populism 2008.ppt

I am delighted by the image they chose to advertise the seminar. Pay no attention to the man behind the curtain.

I like this variation too.
Sociological Institute flyer with megaphone

Populism in Postcommunist Europe: Discussion Transcript, 23.06.2008

Populism in Postcommunist Europe
A panel discussion with regional specialists in political science:

Monday, 23 June 2008 at 15.30
Slovak Foreign Policy Assn., Hviezdoslavovo nám. 14 Bratislava

Thanks to the Slovak Foreign Policy Association, Fulbright Slovakia, the German Marshall Fund, the Department of Political Science of Comenius University, the Institute for Public Affairs, and the Friedrich Ebert Stiftung.

Ben Stanley
Department of Government, University of Essex, UK

Everything is appended to the term populism and so the question is how to make sense of a term that is beset with vagueness?

Populism often turns in the research up as a ‘problem’ conceived of as a pathology, as a disease of normal politics. This feeds into its analysis. Conceptualizations are almost inevitably normative: populism is over-simplified, overpromising, demagogic. The media is particular responsible, tying populism to undesirable phenomena. It becomes difficult to disassociate populism from demagogery itself.

Is populism therefore doomed? Is it simply a grab-bag of political sins, or can it be useful?

I argue that it is useful but within limits; I argue that it is an ideology but is thin. As such it points to very little, and it must be combined with other things to be anything more

The typical approach to populism has been to try to distill its characteristics. One major strain is that of cultural protectivism, cultural exclusism, but these are an attempt to derive a theory of populism from exhibited features. Laclau points out the “avalanche of exceptions.” For every definition, there is another that is sharply contradictory.

According to the definition I have attempted to derive, Populism attempts to identify a people that is homogenous in interests and identity. In ineluctable opposition to this homogeneous people is a homogenous elite.

In addition there is the promise of returning popular sovereignty to politics (the elites have torn populism away from its roots and it is necessary to restore correct balance). The degree of the popular element has been neglected.

There is also a moral dichotomy. It is not enough to describe them as ontologically different but also normatively different. Within the people is an essential purity which, when popular sovereignty is realized, rights the moral balance.

Since populism is by-definition anti-establishment. Its shape is determined by the values of the elite. The elites are easy to envision but is it possible to envision a people that is relatively stable, permanent. In the past, this was possible in terms of, say, a peasant class. Now the degree of ideological work that people must undertake is complicated by the fluidity of identity.

Populism is therefore a strategic addition to other ideologies. Across Europe the processes of globalization provide a fertile soil for populism. As the possibility of alternative economic system disappears, populists can identify on the basis of opposition to the elite rather than a particular economic class.

David Ost
Department of Political Science, Hobart and William Smith Colleges, USA

I have spent a lot of time in Poland over time, and as I think about the term populism, I’m skeptical about the negative connotation.

The way it is increasingly used in Europe, West and East, it is often simply a charge by liberals, especially economic liberals, who feel excluded that others are being “irrational” and it is a way of keeping people from making claims about economic inequality.

The way the term is used is already used is one that includes a moral dimension.

The other reason that I’m skeptical is that I’m an American. In America the word has a different meaning and Hillary Clinton was frequently characterized as a ‘populist.’ After 2004 the Democrats in the United States had a sense that they were being outflanked by a party that focused on cultural values. The American policy magazine The American Prospect has explicitly endorsed a “populist agenda” that seemed to have a significant role in 2008. Democrats began to talk about real economic issues, popular issues. In the United States it does not necessarily have the connotation of demagogery.

My basic argument is that populism the term, and the demagogic aspects come from the fact that it is difficult to organize class-based appeals in an era of democratization. This has a lot to do with the crisis of the left, the crisis of social democracy. The old measures do not work in an era of globalization but a lot of the economic problems remain and need a new language to express them, which helps produce the phenomenon of populism. As long as left parties believed in and could carry out redistribution, social democracy rather than populism was the ‘other’ to economic liberalism. That is not as true anymore.

Populism is a political style that focuses on emotions. When social democracy was more potent, it too had a strong emotional quality (focusing on inclusion) but it was also tied to a specific set of policies of redistribution, so it was not simply emotional appeals but rather emotional connection to specific policies. Oddly it is the intellectual and programmatic basis that cost it support.

The main reason we hear more about populism is that left wing political appeals have declined. We did not hear much about populism between about 1910 and 1970 when the left was strong. Populism was more important in the strong 19th century tradition in Russia. The next popular use of it came in the early 1900’s by those whose enemy was Wall Street, bit corporate capitalism (as opposed to small scale production). In much of the world after the 1910’s, however, these desires for economic equality got taken over in by an emerging Marxist discourse. Economic discourse could be more easily expressed in those terms, and it included a clear program.

By around the 1970’s the social democratic efforts worked in a variety of states to a variety of degrees, but globalization created changes in the labor structure, complicating class structure, labor process, reduction of physical labor so that classes and class conflict did not make much sense anymore.

What emerged then and became dominant after 1989 was a sense that there is no alternative, that the only thing to be done was to remove barriers. But of course this led to a backlash. Those who became the new liberal elites denounced others as populists. This does not mean that some “populist” leaders did not use misuse the search for “economic alternatives” to pursue other agendas (Meciar and the Kaczyinskis come to mind) but when we think about this, it is liberals, particularly economic liberals who bear responsibility for this because they were the ones who repeated that there was no alternative to market capitalism and, in effect, told anybody with objections: “you’re irrational, you’re not making any sense, you’re dumb.” In asserting that there was no alternative, liberals drive others into the populist discourse.

Ann-Cathrine Jungar
University College Stockholm, Sweden

David is arguing that the cause of populism is that there is too little economic choice in politics; I would like to argue that one of the reason for populism is that there is too little politics in politics.

Populism is one of the most disputed concepts in political science. Many claim that it is useless and fruitless. Today we all sit here arguing that there is something in the concept. It can and should be stripped of its normative connotations (not that we should not criticize messages that we think are wrong). What is the alternative? It is a richer conception than “new political parties” or “anti-establishment” political parties.

My way into this is to study populism as a political expression. It is no longer temporary eruptions of political protest but rather an institutionalized opposition. Parties with populist appeals are in parliaments, in the EU parliament. They make and break governments; they force governments to pay attention to programmatic questions.

I lead a project in on populism and we deal with three populist dilemmas:

The first is the dilemma of populism and liberal democracy. This is an uneasy relationship. Populism portrays democratic institutions as unrepresentative and unresponsive. Political processes have become more complex, by a multitude of actors and levels. Agencies and organizations play a role at all levels. Responsibility and accountability is blurred and distance among political elites is diminished. Complexity of societies and politics has created a demand for simpler, more straightforward. Does that mean they provide a distinct vision? Populism resents institutionalization, particularly institutions that restrict the will of the people. Some encourage more direct democracy. Some encourage less constitutionalization with regard minority rights but in other cases, they may seek stronger constitutional mechanisms to force accountability to the people. Populists specify the popular will but they are actually quite vague about it.

Populist parties differentiate themselves from other parties in terms of their greater directness and lower levels of bureaucratization, but over time they tend to undergo a process of political institutionalization which seems to be necessary for survival, but which contradicts their initial goals and founding methods. Do they accept sources of institutionalization? Are they replaced internally with more democratic structures? Populist parties tend to voice a criticism of the state of democracy in general but within themselves the state of democracy is quite low.

The third dilemma is between populism and internationalization/transnationalization. Populists tend to define themselves in terms of particular groups or a heartland with particular values or goals. There is therefore a tendency to focus on domestic problems, issues and to reject external interference and involvement and yet now they are participating in international networks, in the European Parliament and elsewhere, particular visible in the right wing populists.

Peter Učeň
Department of Political Science, Comenius University, Slovakia

I was supposed to populism in Slovakia but I will not–because somebody is going to ask about it and so we can talk about it in the discussion.The search for populism as a meaningful political science category. I want to talk about what Ben talked about in a much more concrete way.

There is such a thing as political competition in which politicians argue against opponents, throw labels. Within this discourse, populists are those with unacceptable views and unacceptable means. I have a big problem with the ‘metaphysical threat’ of populism because I do not understand what those means, what those methods are in a democracy. Setting these limits of unacceptabilities is extremely difficult. If you are too left, too redistributionist, you may be called populist; if you are too right, especially too religious, you may be called populist. Other usual accusations include “irresponsible promises,” appeal to emotions and a last one is “irresponsible criticism of the government.” A Slovak economist defined it as “irresponsible promising to people of things they do not need.” This is obviously quite problematic

Direct appeal to the people–this is the normal practice of politicians where as focus on program and avoidance of emotions is not particularly distinctive.

Another assumption is that all of these things are “insincere,” that this is a “business of lying.” By this standard the populist’s claim to speak for the people is seen as lies and deception.

The first step is admitting it as an ideology. At another point we will have to make a statement from populism as a way of doing politics. In order to think fruitfully about populism, we need to think more clearly about the ideology itself and what it really involves: anti-establishment appeals? anti-incumbency appeals? political demagoguery? political opportunism? We must discuss how these are different, how they are conceptually different and what they have in common while acknowledging that they sometimes travel together.

Question Period

Audience Member: How can science look at populism from a little higher level, at elitism, globalism, the legitimacy from the point of view of money. How is it possible to go higher, to look from a higher position to see if we can find some broader patterns. In Slovakia when you speak about populism you must be prepared for one question: What happened during the first period of privatization when a huge share of national property moved into the hands of foreign owners. This is why the current government is preparing a new strategy of transformation.

Peter Ucen: The question of what happened in the first couple of years of post communism is really crucial. But as the years pass, people are a bit more relaxed about this. It plays less of a role

David Ost: Those who are do not like populists get the question: “you say you don’t like populism but why did national property end up in foreign hands.” The answer—“there was no alternative”—was a historic mistake by liberals. Answers about economy need to take into account people’s attachment related to their jobs, to their properties and there are certain sensitivities that are not taken into account. Liberals often believe that “there are no alternatives,” and “people will just not understand.” But even if they are formally correct—and I do not think that they are—it is not good politics and simply drives people into the hands of so-called populisms.

Ben Stanley: key here is the discourse of authenticity and legitimacy that was violated by the transition. Parts of the transition were ‘disembodied’–it had to be done (it was thought) without asking the people about their actual interests. It also has an identitarian aspect in that cultural identities are violated. Transformation was experienced as a violation of the primary political expectation that people would be at the center of political transformation. The removal of politics from ‘people’ during the early transition has a long legacy. This line of division is potentially potent.

Ann-Cathrine Jungar: We need comparative research, concepts to help us to understand, calls for comparisons but within Europe and elsewhere as well. How would you understand that we have populists both in the older democracies as well as new ones? Are there explanations for what happen that transcend this difference. In the east we have replacement of nomenklatura with economic elite and EU accession; there is a similar feeling with many older democracies that the EU is over involved. It is intriguing to see which are the similarities and differences. Maybe it is possible that populism is not that bad at all; maybe it is a useful mechanism to provide voice to people who otherwise feel shut out; it may actually increase turnout and get people engaged.

David Ost: When populism focus on these economic issues, then they are useful; to the extent that they focus on identity and politics of exclusion, then it becomes problematic. If they focus on equality, this is the way to provide for democratic inclusion.

Ann-Cathrine Jungar: Populism might therefore be part of a dynamic process.

Sona Szomolanyi, Department of Political Science, Comenius University: Experience we have after the elections of 2006 in the Visegrad countries. We had to face many analyses coming mainly from Western analyses that populism is increasing and that it is dangerous for these countries–it is an a priori Western assumptions. Despite the fact that there is a relative precise defintion, given what you’ve talked about, what isn’t a populist party. It is hard to talk about any party in such a way that it does not seem populist. Given the ways that US candidates for president have appeals to voters and the way that East Central European leaders here. It is difficult to see a difference between Obama and Fico. I disagree with David Ost’s argument that there was an assumption that there was no alternative. I don’t think that the social state has been extinguished here in Slovakia (despite the so-called radical reforms of the 2nd Dzurinda government). The level of poverty here is one of the lowest in Europe; the figures on the welfare state do not show its elimination. Perhaps better to avoid the term populism and to focus on empirical operationalizations and aspects.

Ben Stanley: I would certainly agree with the last. One of the problems with it is the attempt to define and disagree. Some methodological common ground is those of us on the panel have tried to do. And its something also that colleagues that colleagues in Western Europe have begun to do. It is becoming more coherent, but we are still in our early days. We are still trying to convince one another that there is common ground.

David Ost: To take issue in another way, it is not that parties did not deviate from a strict market argument but the presumption that it was somehow illegitimate to offer an alternative, and that liberal media elites and those in the international community would not object. I would not necessarily defend Meciar’s policy but at least those policies held to a certain defense of popular economic protection. There certainly has been an effort by some Western liberals to look down on Central and Eastern European for not chosing their model (particularly the American model).

Ann-Cathrine Jungar: I want to talk to your question, “Isn’t there populism everywhere?” Most of us would agree that this is not a dichotomy but a question of degree; we must be more specific. There are a lot of terms we use in political science that we use in ordinary speech so we need to break it down and do specific research on specific terms: how is the people is defined? how “defined” is the people? Do we talk about classes, social interests, appeals to specific groups? We need to try to avoid what Sartori calls “conceptual stretching” Some are more populist than others.

David Ost: I don’t think its a really useful to determine this because in democratic society because you need to do this or you will lose. Obama’s problem is that he has not been populist enough and he is only recently catching up. Bush was different, turning from class antagonisms based on wealth to ones based on education (the real elites are “the educated” (i.e. the over-educated)).

Ann-Cathrine Jungar: I wonder how populism is different from other similar concepts. It seems in theory to be easy to study “Social Democracy” because there is a party group, but if you really looked at them without a party label, without a group in Europarliament it is really hard to see what they have in common.

Ben Stanley: You can look at populism in terms of its recursive nature: one of the most common phrases is a notion of a “populist moment.” We need to stop the endless theorization to see if anything substantial can be made of this. I do not think there is a problem with having a theory of populism and also cocepts from which it is composed. In theorizing it, I think there is a reason for thinking about it; whether this pans out in reality is the direction in which we should be going.

Peter Ucen: I don’t think that everybody is populist. The line is not clear cut but it is reasonable. It is not only true that some are more populist than others, but some are differently populist. With regard to populism in America, it is used in at least 2 different ways: one is socio-economic distribution, (health care); another is more relevant is the anti-establishment (every American president runs against the establishment, claims that they will take control away from those “guys in Washington.”)

Ben Stanley: it is in the nature of political concepts to take on a life of their own outside of the academy. But of late a whole variety of politicians have begun to “claim” the negatives of populism as positive (“if all of those things are populism, then, “yes” I am a populist.”)

Joerg Forbrig, German Marshall Fund: The key would seem to be what happens when these people are in office. In the west how many have been re-elected? Have they implemented their policies? What is the current Slovak government actually doing in terms of policy that might be considered populist. What do populists really do once in office? Can we reduce social support for populists to the “losers” (If I’m not mistaken, PiS won Warsaw first, not the regions of greatest “loss”).

Ben Stanley: There are good grounds for doubting that ‘objective losers’ are the sole support for these parties, but we do need to make a distinction between those who have been left out and those who can be mobilized in terms of a rhetoric of being left out. Kaczynski won Warsaw as mayor but on the basis of arguing that the reins of power had been seized by the red-pink coalition of liberals and nomenklatura and taken it out of the hands of ordinary people. He introduced thereby a different discourse of winners and losers. Obviously in Warsaw it’s not possible to push the economic winners and losers too strongly. Similar, Samoobrona has benefited from support of (in quite objective terms) quite prosperous farmers whose only problem with previous governments is that they are not more prosperous.

Peter Ucen: There is a thesis that populism is the resort of losers, but that assumes that the only kind of losing is economic. Other dimensions of ‘abandoment, betrayed’ are equally or more important. Populism is not business as usual for politicians but it is increasing. With regard to a litmus test from governing–it is difficult. Populists do not often get into power. This also assumes that something about populism is related to program and policy, but this is often quite fragile once it is power. It is important not to think about populism as being about redistribution. Regardless of what a populist politician says, the core is in something else.

Ann-Cathrine Jungar: A variety of populist politicians are still there, are durable, such as LePen and some others. Many of these leaders make a strong career at the local level and broaden that. These parties also have a variety of programmatic goals that they do bring into the mainstream. Some may succeed to remain in power whereas others disappear. That, however, is the interesting research question.

Ben Stanley: Behavior in power is no more of a litmus test than for any other ideological strain. But we can benefit from looking at the party system as a whole. Are these parties consistently able to affect the parties in terms of the issues that are debated within the system, considered to be of import. We ought to be looking at populist parties not simply as populist parties but as those that combine populism with something else. We need to look at populism as an element of appeal and the ideology to which it allies its policies. Populists don’t look to seize power to be populists; they look to do it to achieve some other goal, for ends that connect to their other ideologies.

Ann-Cathrine Jungar: There is also considerable research on how populist parties do influence political outcomes by influencing the broader discourse, even if they are not in power themselves.

Ben Stanley: One of the sources of popularity of Civic Platform in Poland was a tempered, softened liberalism but not as populist, not pushed as hard, not in a permanent mobilization, permanent campaign.

Audience member: There seems to be some theoretical confusion. You’ve mentioned that parties use populism to get into power, but Slovakia’s Smer continues to use anti-establishment appeals even though it is still in government? How is this possible?

Ben Stanley: It’s not that parties in power cannot use anti-establishment appeals but it does get more difficult. It is difficult to sustain a politics of populism and make the compromises necessary to stay in.

David Ost: I’m not sure why it cannot work that those in power cannot use anti-establishment appeals. Kaczynski made a particular mess of it by arguing constantly that there were enemies around with no letup, no respite. We’re seeing all kinds of changes in party politics. Probably a party using anti-estabishment elites can’t endlessly be in power but it probably can do it for a long time.

Question: Marek Rybar, Department of Political Science, Comenius University: I would really like to ask you to tell us what is the added value of populism. What does it explain better than other concepts?

Peter Ucen: This was an expected question and not asked for the first time. When I was asked for the first time, I didn’t have an answer. Three years later, I have an answer. Now I am convinced that there is. The term populism–I’m going to be very practical–political scientists of your level could explain this with other terms but it would be very long. Populism if properly defined makes the explanations shorter.

Ann-Cathrine Jungar: I started by saying that there are other terms that can be used. Many of my Swedish colleagues talk about “new parties”–but there are some distinct characterists: popular sovereignty, the people, anti-elite, and so on. There are historical legacies in how populism expresses itself. Others talk about “anti-establishment parties”–that is actually poorer than populism its potential for operationalization. It would be really interesting to do a paper on the connections among these concepts. Finally, what about all the voters? Are they fooled? They actually believe this but this actually reflects that people should have an influence on politics; they have not yet turned into cynics. And it is interesting that in this era of individuals that we are talking about “community.” It is problematic if it is too exclusive but it clearly reflects a longing for gemeinschaft. They formulate some dreams that we have about populism. Populism is saying something about populism today; dreams and hopes about ordinary people and something about establishment politicians who are not taking the responsibility that they should.

David Ost: I’m probably the most skeptical of the term but we don’t have to abandon it. We might ask why use categories of justice or democracies. I think populism is a political style, a kind of appeal, an endless phenomenon–because the principle is to appeal to the people and there are always possibilities for groups that feel excluded to use it as political entrepreneurs to make an appeal to the people. To give it up entirely would be a problem. It’s useful. It means something. Populism does tell us something, but it doesn’t tell us very much.

Ben Stanley: My justification would be essentially that it is something I hit upon at the start of my own studies as an intellectual problem. There are various definitions from which I attempted to extract a theoretical core. Is there something coherent in this? Do they actually find these linked together in the political appeals of particular parties. It is therefore an empirical research problem. To those who wonder why I study this, I often ask whether the competing concepts do any better. The field moves forward by proposing concepts and discarding them when they do not work and building on them when they do. I think that is our task here.

Populism in Postcommunist Europe: Resources

In recent days I have discovered a large number of new (and relatively new) resources on populism in Central and Eastern Europe. Lists and brief descriptions are here:

Reminder: Populism Discussion, Monday 23 June, 15.30 SFPA

Just a reminder about Monday’s discussion, free and open to all who wish to attend. Graphic is here, text is below. Next week I will try to post notes and perhaps audio or video I can arrange it. Thanks to Fulbright Slovakia, the Friedrich Ebert Stiftung, the Institute for Public Affairs, the Department of Political Science of Comenius University, and the German Marshall Fund for their support in organizing and publicizing the event:

Populism discussion flyer

Beyond Good and Evil? What political scientists have to say about
Populism in Postcommunist Europe

What do we mean when we talk about populism?

How does populism work?

What tools do we have to study it?

Why is populism important for the future,
both in the East
and the West?

What: A panel discussion with regional specialists in political science:

  • Kevin Deegan-Krause, Dept. of Political Science, Wayne State University, USA
  • Ann-Cathrine Jungar, University College, Stockholm, Sweden
  • David Ost, Department of Political Science, Hobart and Smith Colleges, USA
  • Ben Stanley, Department of Government, University of Essex, UK
  • Peter Učeň, Department of Political Science, Comenius University, Slovakia

When: Monday, 23 June 2008 at 15.30
Where: Slovak Foreign Policy Assn., Hviezdoslavovo nám. 14 Bratislava
Csákyho palác, 2nd floor, number 22, tel. +421 2 5443 3151
Who: The discussion is open to all. It will take place in English.

Discussion in Bratislava: Populism in Postcommunist Europe

Join us for a discussion of

Populism in

.

Postcommunist

.

Europe

* What is it?
* How should we study it?
* Why should we care?

With political science scholars who study politics in postcommunist Europe, especially in Slovakia and Poland

  • Kevin Deegan-Krause, Department of Political Science, Wayne State University, USA
  • Ann-Cathrine Jungar, CBEES (Centre for Baltic and East European Studies)
    Södertörns högskola/University College Stockholm, Sweden
  • David Ost, Department of Political Science, Hobart and Smith Colleges, USA
  • Ben Stanley, Department of Government, University of Essex, UK
  • Peter Učeň, Department of Political Science, Comenius University, Slovaki

The discussion will take place in English

Where:
Slovak Foreign Policy Association Library, Hviezdoslavovo nám. 14 Bratislava
(Csákyho palác, 2nd floor, number 22, tel. +421 2 5443 3151)

When:
Monday, 23 June 2008 at 15.30

Conference Notes: Social Democracy after the 2006 Elections in Slovakia

Thanks to Michael Petras and Martin Muransky for organizing a fabulous conference:Below please find a few notes from various speakers and at the bottom, the conference schedule in Slovak.

Social Democracy after the 2006 Elections in Slovakia

Bratislava, Slovakia, 23-24 May 2008
Organized by the Friedrich Ebert Stiftung


Social Policy of the Slovak GovernmentJuraj Draxler, Center for European Policy Studies Brusel

Basis of social protection

Correcting for demographics and unemployment, Slovak averages considerably below the Czech Republic and Hungary and even below Poland.

What does this really mean? What is a social state? As viewed in the media, it is “redistribution,” it is “charity.” It also serves other important purposes:

  • Minimize externalities
  • Solve social problems
  • Smooth out economic cycle

When formed it was not just an altruistic effort but also supported by the entrepreneurial sector. In Scandinavia it is extended to system of minimizing risks for individuals, hence large emphasis on unemployment insurance.

Economic background

Slovakia is exceptionally dependent on international market, exceptionally open. We cannot talk about endogenous growth but about influence from abroad. Employment (2004) is to a larger degree than in UK and Germany in small firms. Economic value, on the other hand, is in the larger firms. Slovakia profits from productivity of big firms Small expenditure on research. Natural emphasis on rapid adaptation to western maket. There is a lack of experience that the state has a role in minimizing risk. There is a large population of long-term unemployed.

Not in a typical “industrial state” in which workers spend entire lives in one firm. Now there is an expectation (requirement) of far greater flexibility. Currently there is a big debate related to working with “znalost,” knowledge workers.

Experience of long-term unemployed in UK suggests that this is becomes a culture question which, once created, is difficult to eradicate.

Who creates social policy in Slovakia.

  • Unions? In West, unions play a role, classic tripartite-model, whereas in Slovakia this is not the case. Every kind of activity—strikes, organization—is lower than in the West.
  • Electorate? Only through parties
  • Governing parties? Slovakia has centralized, paternalistic state. What the center decides is done. This can have some advantage: only one system, easy to change. But because so centralized, system is dependent on government/parties that are in charge.

Places of conflict?

  • Negotiations of interest groups
  • Public debates
  • Technical/Technocratic debates.

Smer’s Voters: A Sociological PortraitOľga Gyarfášová, IVO a Vlado Krivý, Sociologický ústav SAV

Adherents before 2006 elections

Charts show growth in voters for “left” and center-right parties

Smer voters not distinct in their views of the direction of the countries—not overwhelmingly dissatisfied with direction of the country (more like SNS than KSS and HZDS). It is not to that extent much of a protest parties.

Value orientation does not look overwhelmingly different from average (slightly more opposed to reform and church but not much else).

Left from a socioeconomic perspective but lacks anything else.

On left-right axis slightly greater in weak left and weaker in weak right on self-declared. On latent (ascribed values) almost identical to population as a whole.

Smer has shifted somewhat to the east and overwhelmingly to smaller towns, rural space.

In 2002 party did best in big (but not the biggest) cities. In 2006 party did best in smallest communities, 2nd best in 20k to 49k. Smer won lots of votes from HZDS, KSS and HZD.

Voters of Smer in 2006 and supporters in 2007

In 50 categories, Smer differed from population only in 14, 8 of which were regions. Otherwise, Smer did better only in only low education, small towns, lower occupational class, and worse only in both higher and basic education and those with lowest wages.

No clear gain from other parties (mainly from novoters, first voters, undecided) Most Smer voters stayed in Smer.

Fico second most popular individual for both SNS and HZDS (Slota is third for HZDS, Gasparovic is 3rd for Smer while Kalinak is second). Leaders have much higher value among current governing parties than among current opposition parties.

Comparative study suggests that slovakia has smaller right and larger center than other countries in the region but no smaller leftand about average number of “unknowns”

Compared to other “Left” parties, Smer has lowest level of left voters. Smaller by 13 points than CSSD, by 27 points than Poland’s LiD, by 31 points than MSZD and by 15 points than SZDSZ.

National left and right are closer to each other than to similar parties from other countries. National context is more important than ideological one [though if reduced to a single axis, with “abortion” removed, this effect disappears.]

Oponent – Pavol Marchevský, UVVM

Researchers must work with the work they have.

4 Points relevant to the presentation

  1. Value orientation of Smer, most mainstream (visible in publications as well)
  2. Difference between self-declared and latent values. In self-declared, most are center. In “real terms” they are much more to the left”
  3. Smer—party that got 29 percent in election now has 43. First time voters support them overwhelming. National values are more important than economic values in shaping left and right
  4. Lacks a time-perspective. Need to use long time-series. Qualitative change. Structure of the electorate shifted toward different kinds of voters [more disciplined ones]. Before the 2002 elections, Smer had only 4 among the oldest voters (the ones who go and vote). In January 2006 they had 25 percent, and those voters go and vote. Notion is that Smer is general without army, and that Smer would get 1/3 less than before. But UVVM knew that Smer really had the voters. Already 1 year after creation, Smer had 20, by a year before 2006 had 40. But the voters earlier were less disciplined, diametrically opposed. Now Smer has numbers over 40 percent. (Means in practice that university educated still prefer Smer 2-1)

Social weakest are voters of KSS and HZDS more than Smer. They also do not go and vote.


The National Pillar in the Politics of SmerPavel Hynčica, Filozofická fakulta Univerzity Jana Evangelisty Purkyně v Ústí nad Labem

More unites Smer a SNS than divides them.

National appeals in the party Smer. Increase of national appeals has its deeper roots.

Early in the party’s existence a variety of efforts about Roma, made party closer to the SNS. After election 2002 the left-right scale strengthened. Profiled mainly on socioeconomic lines. Reflected in support for HZD candidate Gasparovic in presidence and cooperation in elections.

Oponent Peter Weiss, Ekonomická univerzita Bratislava

One problem, perhaps basically, comparison of program shows difference. But must compare to other parties. Other parties, too, show that their programs are similar, including also KDH. Must look at other parties—HZDS, KDH and compare also to those other parties. Must look especially to HZDS for comparision.

Must look also at “HSLS” history and role it plays in current parties.

Must look also at position of Smer toward Tiso, toward Holocaust which is quite different from SNS.

Dislikes Smer’s approval of Hlinka as father of the nation which undermined leftism of party (whether for genuine or “marketing” reasons.

Problem of immigration and “different” social groups could become an issue, even if it is not yet. This would strengthen conservatism in Slovakia.

After its founding in 1999, Smer proved capable of getting not only voters of SDL but those of HZDS; without national appeals it couldn’t have done it.


Populist Appeals in Slovakia’s PoliticsKevin Deegan-Krause, Department of Political Science, Wayne State University

Please contact me for the full text. I will try to post it soon.

Thanks to all of the participants for their great questions. Here’s a rough summary.

Questions:

  • Is it licit to treat parties as unitary actors, particularly SDK and MK before 1998. These parties are really multiple actors?
  • Does the ‘dominant position of the leader’ really belong within concepts of populism. Is it necessary? Personalization and ‘presidentialization’ seem to be the common trend these days.
  • Should all of these elements have equal weight in the creation of the scale?
  • Can the
  • What is the role of the media in this? Do they play an independent role?
  • To what extent did Smer set out to build a social democratic party or to what extent did they set out to build an electorally successful party and later opted for social democracy as the key to that success?
  • What explains the rise of populist appeal scores for SNS?
  • Many of the parties in Slovakia’s governments have been new parties with highly populist appeals that then die off: ZRS, SOP, ANO. To what extent will we expect such a pattern to contrinue?
  • Shouldn’t features such as “making promises that cannot be fulfilled” and “close following of public opinion, popular preferences” be included as elements of populism?
  • Is there a long term “populist type” of voter, somebody who regularly votes for new parties? Does this mean a long-term populist issue divide?

Economic Policy in Slovakia and its Impacts—Comparison with the V4
Zdeněk Lukáš, Wiener Institut fuer Internationale Wirtschaftsvergleiche
What do the V4 have in common

  • Average incomes
  • Average wage levels
  • Overall price levels

Fully in line with lower degree of development and therefore lower labor productivity

Low in comparison to V4 but rapidly catching up

Incomes PPP

  • CZ from 69 in 2002 to 81 in 2007
  • SK from 51 in 2002 to 69 in 2007
  • HU from 54 in 2000 to 61 in 2007
  • PL from 48 in 2007 to 54 in 2007

Wages in EUR

  • CZ from 400 in 2002 to 800 in 2007
  • SK from 270 in 2002 to 600 in 2007
  • HU from 300 in 2000 to 700 in 2007
  • PL from 480 in 2007 to 700 in 2007
  • Austria, for comparison form 2390 in 2000 to 2762 in 2007

Slovakia remains very attractive for foreign investors

Price level compared to EU

  • CZ from 40 in 2002 to 60 in 2007
  • SK from 40 in 2002 to 60 in 2007
  • HU from 45 in 2000 to 60 in 2007
  • PL from 45 in 2007 to 60 in 2007

Difference is still marked

Also in common—improving trade balance in spite of catching up of wages and prices

Not quite in common: Improving financial balances. CZ, SK and PL all in balance, Hungary far below.

Other policy features in common: emphasis on attracting foreign direct investment, priority of reforms on social security

Admiration for Anglo-Saxon/Hayekian approaches

Heading for Slim states

  • CZ from 55 in 2002 to 47% in 2007
  • SK from 48 in 2002 to 50% in 2007
  • HU from 53 in 2000 to 47% in 2007
  • PL from 47 in 2007 to 38% in 2007 (major difference coming in around 2003)
  • EU 15 average is 46.2%

What are the differences

Average income

Discrepancy between rich and poor (social inclusion and exclusion: periphery and poverty). Bratislava v. far eastern sections

Problems with transport net but in respect to the west, is functional

Reform radicalism—more in some countries than in others

Influence of populism—not much seen in Slovakia between 1998-2006

Ideas about the role of the EU—Euroskeptics in CZ (now) and (until recently) PL

Lessons

  • In the end the V4 transition was a success thanks to exchange rates which secured competitiveness
  • Within the EU there is plenty of space for economic success or poor performance, e.g. Ireland vs. Greece, Sweden v. Italy, Slovakia vs. Hungary and plenty of space for good and bad policies
    • Slovakia has success in part because of Fico’s continuation of Dzurinda’s economic course. It would have been difficult to do anything differently since this was the locomotive of current growth. If Dzurinda government had continued after 2006, it would have engaged in the same generous social policy as Fico because it finally would have had the means.
  • Some V4 experiences contradictory to rule that low interest rates provokes inflation

Slovakia’s economy, now and later

  • Slovakia remains an attractive location for foreign investment
  • Could overheating push prices and wages too high, create labor market shortage in some segments? (probably has not been a major problem with inflation, because of greater increases in productivity than wages)
  • 10.4% growth plus 2.8% inflation is remarkable and raises concerns about future in inflation, particularly in goods and services for those with below-average income.
    • In Slovakia there is a major competition in supermarkets and similar stores unlike, for example, Slovenia, which should keep some Euro risks lower.
  • For country with 10.$ growth, budget deficit was rather high (2.2% of GNP). This does not look alarming in light of relatively low government debt (29.4%)

Will government have sufficient funds, even if lower GDP growth

Key tasks:

  • Upgrading educational system (a key for future success)
  • Upgrading infrastructure (a key for future success)
  • Fight against impoverishment and social exclusion)
  • EU cofinancing requires domestic resources and skills

Questions from the audience

  • What explains the sharp drop in government expenditure in Slovakia in 2003? Growth in the economy? Drop in generosity of social benefits? What is the state of productivity?
  • Productivity of work has regularly (though not always) exceeded rise in prices.
  • Spain is an interesting case for comparison in regard to “approximation”
  • Can you compare foreign investment between the Czech and Slovak direct foreign investment? Is not it greater in the Czech Republic ? Does the investment have to do with reforms or with cheaper but still qualified workers?
  • Can you talk about automobile industry. Is not making the greatest number of cars per capita about like making the greatest number of tanks per capital. How much time do we have for the next transformation of industrial production?

Party Smer: Populist or Just Popular?
Karen Henderson, University of Leicester -I do not want to do deep analyses of populism or Smer’s program, but rather about how populism became part of Slovak political competition.

Noteworthy in the press that the expression “populism” is used against Smer by every party. If even SNS and HZDS use it then it can only mean “enemy.”

Two parts. First part will analyze use of ‘terminus technicus’ “populist” and “popular” and in the second part I will focus on the fact that the term populism hides more than it reveals. It hides the ‘social democratic’ side of the party Smer. Opposition parties use ‘populist” in order not to deal with the fact that they are not popular.

Populism has a sufficiently brief definition: ideology which sees society as divided into 2 homogenous groups: a pure people and a corrupt elite. They say that “the elites are corrupt. We need better politicians. Need to trade in current elites for somebody new.

Most of the new parties created anew since 1990 have been marked as ‘new’ party. In this sense, populism is simply a political strategy for getting elected and one with a relatively short lifespan once parties get into power. There is the claim that reject complexity, prefer simplicity.

In Slovakia in the last 20 years only 2 politicians have asked “what do voters want” and tried to give it. That is why they get labeled as populist. In many cases this /is/ a problem (majority of Slovaks favor the death penalty). But, political discourse in Slovakia which marks Smer as populist is problematic. On one hand, people criticize Smer as populist; on they other hand they criticize it for not fulfilling its social promises. (The discourse is complicated by the fact that )

One definition suggests that populists have an aversion to representative democracy and prefer direct democracy. Interesting that Dzurinda criticized Fico as populist when both (quietly) cooperated in shifting the argument to economics (right v. left) and then criticized Fico as a populist.

Very typical for leftist parties in Central Europe to have leftist economic position and conservative cultural position.

The hidden question of Slovakia’s current debate is that the current opposition has been incapable of appealing to voters, to figuring out what they want?

Mudde talks about the “populist zeitgeist.” Are politicians today more corrupt than they were before? Maybe there are always new populist parties in Slovakia because the politicians really are corrupted. Everybody thinks that politicians take those positions in order to distribute state property to those close to them. Every government party attacks every other as corrupt.

Oponent Petr Učeň, doktorand na Katedre politológie UK
Karen says that it is important to distinguish between populism and popularity. Peter Levin wrote: “why is there so much discussion of populism in Europe when similar American politicians are regarded as mainstream.”

Karen talks about “eastern” form of social democracy where political leftism is not combined with liberal cultural values and that Smer started as populist but has ended up somewhere else.

It is a populist project which survived, which selectively adopted a leftist economic agenda, and also a social conservative agenda to the extent that it would help the party. Karen says that Smer is a programmatic party. In at least relaxed version, programmatic party is one that refers to its program, and by those standards, Smer is programmatic, but they realize the problems in implementing their program and have preferred to engage in symbols (even if relatively strong ones) such as Christmas gifts for retirees.

Content-based approach at finding core of populism does not lead anywhere. Laclaou: “every discussion of populism leads to an “avalanche of exceptions”

Is populism an ideology or an electoral strategy. Frieden argues that “ideology” is a map of politics, a way of interpret politics. By those standards, populism is an ideology but it is a “thin” (stihla) one. It only talks about one thing. People are not where they should be, politically, and that must change. Populism talks about 4 basic things: political structure divided, fatally antagonist, moral apologetics for public influence on politics. Populism needs, therefore, a compound. It needs to be joined with something else. It is an “adjective” rather than a noun.

Kalinak, Paska are not populists. They can help their leaders but this is not their primary skill.

Interesting that Fico continues to succeed in using anti-establishment rhetoric despite the fact that he is in the elite.


Program odbornej konferencie

 

„Sociálna demokracia po voľbách 2006 na Slovensku“

Piatok 23.5.2008

13,00 – zahájenie Michael Petráš, FES, moderovanie Darina Malová

Sociálna politika slovenskej vlády

Juraj Draxler, Center for European Policy Studies Brusel

diskusia

14,00 -Voliči Smeru – sociologický portrét

Oľga Gyarfášová, IVO a Vlado Krivý, Sociologický ústav SAV
Oponent – Pavol Marchevský, UVVM

diskusia

15,15 – prestávka

15,45 – Národní pilíř v politice SMERu

Pavel Hynčica, Filozofická fakulta Univerzity Jana Evangelisty Purkyně v Ústí nad
Labem

Oponent – Peter Weiss, Ekonomická univerzita Bratislava

diskusia

17,00 – Smer v komparatívnej perspektíve európskych politických strán

Kevin Deegan-Krause, Wayne State University
Oponent – Lubomír Kopeček, Masarykova universita Brno

diskusia

cca 18,30 – recepcia, spoločné neformálne posedenie

Sobota 24.5.2008

09,00 moderovanie Oľga Gyarfášová

Hospodářska politika na Slovensku a její dopady – komparace s V4
Zdeněk Lukáš, Wiener Institut fuer Internationale Wirtschaftsvergleiche

diskusia

10,00 – SMER: od pragmatizmu k sociálnej demokracii

Luboš Bláha, Politologický kabinet SAV a Robert Žanony
Oponent – Peter Horváth, UCM Trnava

diskusia

11,15 – prestávka

11,45 – Strana Smer-SD – populistická alebo populárna?

Karen Henderson, University of Leicester
Oponent – P. Učeň, doktorand na Katedre politológie UK

diskusia

cca 13,30 – záver a spoločný obed

Central European University Political Science, Annual Doctoral Conference, Session II

Since I talked today about blogging as an academic took, it seems only right that I would do a bit of live-blogging from the session that followed my own. Here are a few thoughts. Apologies to anyone whose ideas I have mischaracterized:

Oana Lup
The Role of Political Talk in Developing Democracies: Evidence from Hungary
Abstract Paper
discussant: Reka Varnagy

Everyday political talk seen as a border case: not quite ordinary talk but not quite political discourse. Evidence is ambiguous and often contradictory.

Being embedded in a larger or more politicized network does not make a significant difference in turnout once the most important part of social interaction is controlled for (relationship status, employment)

Those with more discussants are also more likely to make correct use of left-right heuristic.

Juraj Medzihorsky
Intellectuals, Think Tanks, and Politics in CEE
Abstract Paper
discussant: George Florea

Think tanks occupy the space between politics, academics, business and journalism. In the US, it was within this sphere with strong relationships to academia and business. In Central and Eastern Europe, initial think tanks existed in a realm with the above space but anchored on a fifth side by Western donors. Since then, however, Western donors have shifted their emphasis regionally away from CEE, think tanks have to make a choice between business or politics or to follow the Western donors’ shift in emphasis and begin focusing outside of CEE. In Slovakia, the choice seemed idiosyncratic.

Reka Varnagy (Corvinus University)
The Role of Local Politics in the Carrier Path of Political Elites
Abstract Paper
discussant: Eszter Simon

Supply Side:Governments and parties structured according to differentiated political space and territorially structured hierarchy.

Hypothesis: The movement of political career fueled by progressive ambition is unidirectional.

Local politics can be seen as a springboard or as a base office as part of a process of cumulation. Hypothesis: cumulation seems preferable. Leaders see it as the local level as a base.

Demand Side

Parties are a dominant factor with alternatives unusual.

Hypothesis: political elites with local background will become party members early in in their political career.

Empirical data: using members of parliaments who are also mayors, ladder goes in both direction. Large share of Hungarian mayors were members of parliaments /first/ before funning for mayor.

Mats Ohlen (Orebro University)
Transnational Party Cooperation in Post 1989 Europe: European Christian Democrats and affiliated parties in East Central Europe
Abstract Paper
discussant: Oana Lup
There is a triangular relationship between the European Party, the parliamentary party group and the individual national parties. Because there is a relatively weak coordination between national parties and the parliamentary party group, the European Party plays an important role in disseminating information. The European Parties also play a role in deciding who can join–which in the end means “who ‘exists'”.

In 1989 only three European parties existed: EPP, PES and ELD. Brief History: EUCD created in 1965, quite strict about membership. In 1976 EPP is created but do not admit UK and Denmark. They form EDU (of conservative parties). EPP holds dominant power position. In 1992 EPP and EDU starts to reunite. From 1995-1999, CEE parties transfer to EPP.

Problems for EPP: goal of breadth (broad inclusion) and depth (supporting Christian ideal). Must balance two.

Poland had difficult party landscape: 6 Christian Democratic parties in 1992.

EPP is represented in all EU parties in UK and is the biggest party group in the EP. EUCD served as buffer zone and waiting room. Increasing pragmatism about whom to permit.